3.2. Policy assessment
К оглавлению1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 1617 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33
34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50
51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59 60 61 62 63 64 65 66 67
68 69 70 71 72 73 74 75 76 77 78 79 80 81 82 83 84
85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94
In thinking about how to intervene in the world, we often have need for
beliefs about what sorts of policies (general strategies for dealing with
certain situations) are effective and which are not effective. For example,
many people have opinions about what sorts of social policies are best
suited to overcoming poverty in our country. These opinions (we hope)
rest on judgments about the effectiveness of various social policies; and these judgments (we hope) rest on good evidence. But what counts as
good evidence for thinking that a social policy has been effective? Long
and technical books have been written about policy analysis. While we can’t
expect ordinary reasoners to master the complexities of policy analysis, the
consider-the-control strategy might help people to overcome some glaring
errors associated with the assessment of policy.
Policy assessment is applicable to much more than issues of social policy.
It is also relevant to the assessment of different approaches to personal
and professional matters. To take an example close to home, everyone
knows that it’s hard to get good jobs in philosophy. Different people and
schools take different approaches to job searches. At the national conference
where job interviews are conducted, some job seekers are more
aggressive than others about seeking out and chatting up prospective employers
at receptions. Some departments are more aggressive than others
when it comes to lobbying for their graduate students. On the other side of
the job search, different departments take different approaches to the
hiring process. For example, some don’t conduct conference interviews,
while others conduct many short (15-minute) interviews. Which of these
strategies is most effective in finding a job (or hiring a job seeker)? Presumably,
many of our colleagues have firm opinions about these matters—
or at least opinions that are firm enough for them to act on. But does their
evidence support their opinions? We suspect that in most cases, the answer
is no. The reason is that most people involved in the job search don’t
know how well they would have done if they’d adopted different search
policies. (Actually, the truth is a bit more disturbing than this. At least
some of our colleagues know about, or have heard about, the interview
effect; so they have some evidence that their job searches would have
gone, on average, better if they’d not insisted upon short unstructured
interviews.)
We often employ strategies in social matters as well. In trying to
win friends and influence people at a party, we might try being funny or
charming or ‘‘coming on strong’’ or drinking to the point of imbecility. Of
course, often these strategies aren’t consciously adopted—they’re not the
result of an explicit decision procedure in which alternatives are considered
and rejected. But many of us sometimes reflect on our social behaviors
(perhaps after a particularly humiliating episode) and wonder
whether we might try to change our ways in the future in order to obtain
better results. Reflecting on these issues requires that we think about what
social strategies are most likely to help us achieve our social goals. For
many, this is a particularly significant kind of policy assessment.
There is a serious problem associated with policy assessment that
arises as soon as we consider the control. The problem is particularly acute
when it comes to the assessment of large-scale policies or seldom used
policies (like job search policies). The problemis that it’s hard to know how
the world would have been if we hadn’t adopted those policies. Gilovich
(1991) calls this the problem of hidden data (or hidden evidence). For
example, we don’t know what the current state of poverty would be like if
we’d not adopted certain poverty programs; and we don’t know how we’d
have done on the job market if we’d gone about things differently. Since
we can’t turn back time to see how the world would have turned out if
we would have adopted different policies, the best way to deal with the
problem of hidden data is to compare different policies (implemented in
relevantly similar circumstances) against each other. Sometimes, the problem
of hidden data is so severe that we would do better just to accept fewer
causal hypotheses than we do and to be a lot less confident about the ones
we do accept.
In thinking about how to intervene in the world, we often have need for
beliefs about what sorts of policies (general strategies for dealing with
certain situations) are effective and which are not effective. For example,
many people have opinions about what sorts of social policies are best
suited to overcoming poverty in our country. These opinions (we hope)
rest on judgments about the effectiveness of various social policies; and these judgments (we hope) rest on good evidence. But what counts as
good evidence for thinking that a social policy has been effective? Long
and technical books have been written about policy analysis. While we can’t
expect ordinary reasoners to master the complexities of policy analysis, the
consider-the-control strategy might help people to overcome some glaring
errors associated with the assessment of policy.
Policy assessment is applicable to much more than issues of social policy.
It is also relevant to the assessment of different approaches to personal
and professional matters. To take an example close to home, everyone
knows that it’s hard to get good jobs in philosophy. Different people and
schools take different approaches to job searches. At the national conference
where job interviews are conducted, some job seekers are more
aggressive than others about seeking out and chatting up prospective employers
at receptions. Some departments are more aggressive than others
when it comes to lobbying for their graduate students. On the other side of
the job search, different departments take different approaches to the
hiring process. For example, some don’t conduct conference interviews,
while others conduct many short (15-minute) interviews. Which of these
strategies is most effective in finding a job (or hiring a job seeker)? Presumably,
many of our colleagues have firm opinions about these matters—
or at least opinions that are firm enough for them to act on. But does their
evidence support their opinions? We suspect that in most cases, the answer
is no. The reason is that most people involved in the job search don’t
know how well they would have done if they’d adopted different search
policies. (Actually, the truth is a bit more disturbing than this. At least
some of our colleagues know about, or have heard about, the interview
effect; so they have some evidence that their job searches would have
gone, on average, better if they’d not insisted upon short unstructured
interviews.)
We often employ strategies in social matters as well. In trying to
win friends and influence people at a party, we might try being funny or
charming or ‘‘coming on strong’’ or drinking to the point of imbecility. Of
course, often these strategies aren’t consciously adopted—they’re not the
result of an explicit decision procedure in which alternatives are considered
and rejected. But many of us sometimes reflect on our social behaviors
(perhaps after a particularly humiliating episode) and wonder
whether we might try to change our ways in the future in order to obtain
better results. Reflecting on these issues requires that we think about what
social strategies are most likely to help us achieve our social goals. For
many, this is a particularly significant kind of policy assessment.
There is a serious problem associated with policy assessment that
arises as soon as we consider the control. The problem is particularly acute
when it comes to the assessment of large-scale policies or seldom used
policies (like job search policies). The problemis that it’s hard to know how
the world would have been if we hadn’t adopted those policies. Gilovich
(1991) calls this the problem of hidden data (or hidden evidence). For
example, we don’t know what the current state of poverty would be like if
we’d not adopted certain poverty programs; and we don’t know how we’d
have done on the job market if we’d gone about things differently. Since
we can’t turn back time to see how the world would have turned out if
we would have adopted different policies, the best way to deal with the
problem of hidden data is to compare different policies (implemented in
relevantly similar circumstances) against each other. Sometimes, the problem
of hidden data is so severe that we would do better just to accept fewer
causal hypotheses than we do and to be a lot less confident about the ones
we do accept.